background image

 

Position paper  
Prepared for roundtable on ‘(wealth) inequality, economic (in)equality, and taxation 
policy’ on 13 May 2025 
Huub Brouwer, Tilburg University 
8 May 2025 
 

Executive summary 

 

The key findings in this position paper are that in the Netherlands: (1) the gap in life 
expectancy between rich and poor is rising, (2) homeownership is becoming less 
accessible, (3) pillar II pensions are not a great equalizer and should not be counted as 
wealth, and (4) intergenerational wealth concentration is increasing. Given these 
findings, policy interventions are necessary to enhance broad prosperity. I identify three 
low-hanging fruits: (Policy recommendation 1) closing loopholes in the Dutch tax 
system that enable tax avoidance, (P2) reforming capital income taxation, and (P3) 
modernizing and reforming gift and inheritance taxation.  
 
 

A new narrative about wealth inequality 

 

There has been a surge in scientific and societal interest in wealth inequality following 
the publication of Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the Twenty-First Century (2014). He 
argues that in Western countries, wealth-income ratios display a U-shape: they reached 
a peak in the low-tax, low-regulation capitalism of the 19th century, decreased because 
of wars and progressive taxation, and are now on the rise again. To counteract the 
harmful effects of rising wealth-income ratios, Piketty advocates progressive income 
taxation (chp. 14) and worldwide progressive capital taxation (chp. 15). 
 
Waldenström (2024) challenges Piketty’s historical narrative and policy 
recommendations. Drawing on new data and new research on wealth inequality in 
France, Germany, Spain, Sweden, the UK and the US, he argues that Western societies 
are richer and more equal today than they were a hundred years ago. This, according to 
Waldenström, is apparent from a significant rise in life-expectancy, homeownership, 
and pension-savings of those at the bottom and middle of the wealth distribution. Based 
on his historical research, Waldenström advocates for lower income taxation and no 
capital taxation, among other policy measures (chp. 10.2).  
 
In this position paper, I argue that although historical analyses of wealth inequality can 
be a very valuable input for policy, the primary concern for policymakers should be 
developments in and levels of key indicators in the past twenty years, as well as 
predictions on the development of these indicators following recent policy changes. In 
the Netherlands, inequality on the key indicators Waldenström considers (life 
expectancy, homeownership, and pensions) has been rising in recent years. Moreover, 
intergenerational wealth concentration is increasing. These developments threaten to 
undermine broad prosperity.1  

 

1 ‘Broad prosperity’ is a welfare concept that looks beyond direct financial-economic benefits and burdens 
and also weighs the distribution of welfare, the sustainability of welfare for future generations, and the 

background image

 

Facts about inequality in the Netherlands 

 
1: Differences in life-expectancy between rich and poor are significant and growing  
Differences in life expectancy are an important indicator of inequality, and, as 
Waldenström rightly argues, the economically disadvantaged in Western countries have 
witnessed a “dramatic enhancement in life expectancy” over the past century (2024, 
24).  
 
However, there are still substantial differences in life expectancy at birth between the 
rich and poor in the Netherlands (CBS 2022): 
-  Life expectancy at birth for women in the highest wealth quintile is 7,7 years higher 

than for women in the lowest wealth quintile (86 and 78,3 years). For men, the 
difference is 9,3 years (83,1 and 73,8 years).  

-  Healthy life expectancy at birth for women in the highest wealth quintile is 23 years 

higher than for women in the lowest wealth quintile (72 and 49 years). For men, the 
difference is 25 years (74 and 49 years). 

 
Moreover, differences in life expectancy grew between 2005 and 2015 (Muns, Knoef, 
van Soest 2018; similar findings are reported for US by Chetty et al. 2016 – see also SER 
2023):   
-  Life expectancy at age 40 for women in the highest income quintile grew by 1,4 

years, but declined for women in the lowest income quintile by 0,6 years. Hence, 
the difference increased by 2,0 years. 

-  Life expectancy at age 40 for men in the highest income quintile grew by 3,4 years, 

but only grew by 1,6 years for men in the lowest income quintile. Hence, the 
difference increased by 1,8 years. 

 
2: Homeownership is becoming less accessible  
According to Waldenström (2024, 75-89), Western countries are richer and more equal 
primarily because homeownership and capital-funded pensions have greatly increased 
household wealth. 
 
That homeownership is an important driver of household wealth is borne out in data on 
the Netherlands: The net wealth of households with a median income in the age 
bracket 60-69 was 663.000 euros for homeowners, whereas it was only half that 
amount for renters (CBS 2021, 11 – these figures include pension capital).  
 
It is hard to maintain, however, that homeownership will continue to be a great 
equalizer, because it has become unattainable for an increasingly large group over the 
past 30 years:  
-  in 1995, modal gross annual income in the Netherlands was 22.235 euros (CPB 

2024) and the average house price was 93.750 euros (CBS 2025a): hence, the 
average house cost 4,22 times the modal income.  

 

welfare of other countries. CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis is developing a set of 
key indicators for broad prosperity together with PBL and SCP and is integrating these in its economic 
analyses and forecasts over the coming years. See https://www.cpb.nl/brede-welvaart.  

background image

 

-  in 2025, modal gross income is estimated to be 46.500 euros (CBP 2024), and the 

average house price was 470.000 euros during the first quarter (Kadaster 2025): 
hence, the average house now costs 10,11 times the modal income.  

 
3: Pensions are not a great equalizer and should not be counted as wealth 
When it comes to pensions, the Netherlands is often deemed to have the best pension 
system in the world, combining a pay-as-you-go state pension scheme (pillar I), capital 
funded collective pension schemes (pillar II), and individual pension products (pillar 
III). Old-age poverty is very low (except for people aged above 90), which is a 
significant achievement (Hoff & Hulst 2019). 
 
However, it is hard to maintain that pensions are a great equalizer in the Netherlands. 
Importantly, the pillar II pension works according to an insurance principle, not 
according to a savings principle. Retired participants receive a monthly benefit and 
when the participant and their partner pass away, their remaining pension contributions 
are not paid out to the next of kin, but are instead retained by the pension fund.2 Given 
life expectancy differences between the rich and poor in the Netherlands, the poor 
have a much shorter period during which they can draw benefits from their 
contributions than the rich. Also, pensions are unequally distributed between higher 
and lower educated workers3 and between employees and the self-employed.4  
 
A fundamental question here is whether pillar II pension contributions should be 
counted as part of people’s wealth in the first place. These contributions are not 
withdrawable at will, not transferrable, and not otherwise manipulable (for instance, 
individuals cannot decide what their contributions are invested in). The best 
conceptualisation of pillar II pensions, then, is not as wealth in which one has solid 
property rights, but instead as an insurance for an income at old age. Because of this, 
researchers in the Netherlands often exclude pillar II pension contributions from wealth 
inequality statistics (see, for instance, IBO vermogensverdeling 2022 – for discussion, 
see Toussaint 2024, 5).  
 
4: Intergenerational wealth concentration is increasing 
An important claim in Waldenström’s book is that the U-shaped pattern in wealth-
income ratios reported by Piketty (2014), among others, is the result of overestimating 
wealth-income ratios for the late 19th and early 20th century.  
 

 

2  In  the  future,  participants  will  be  able  to,  if  the  Senate  passes  a  bill  on  this  that  has already  passed 
Parliament, request 10% of their pension capital to be transferred to them upon retirement. 

3 The highly educated aged above 75 on average have €246.000 of pension capital, whereas people with 
lower education in the same age group have €58.000. See Arts & Pouwels-Urlings (2020) for details and 
appendix 1 for additional statistics for other age groups.  
4

 To see this, consider a common measure of adequate old-age pension: whether people’s total pension 

income (combining pillar I, II, and III) equals at least 70% of their gross annual income before retirement. 
It turns out that self-employed workers, non-Western immigrants and welfare recipients are much more 
likely to have a replacement ratio of gross annual income below 70%. At median incomes, the share of 
self-employed workers who are faced with a below 70% replacement ratio is 11 percentage points higher 
than for employees. In the highest income quintile, this difference is 19 percentage points (Knoef et al. 
2017).

 

background image

 

However, empirical research on the Netherlands (Toussaint et al. 2024), does not only 
find a U-shaped pattern in wealth-income ratios, but also one of the highest 19th 
century wealth-income ratios on record: of 700% around 1880. Toussaint et al. (2024) 
argue that this particularly pronounced U-shape can be explained by colonial and other 
foreign investment during the 19th century, and the widespread introduction of capital-
funded collective pensions during the 20th century. 
 
Recent research shows that the richest 10% currently hold 62% of wealth, and the 
richest 1% hold 26% of wealth in the Netherlands (IBO vermogensverdeling 2022, 5). 
In the medium to long term, wealth can be passed down within families through gifts 
and inheritance. A recent study finds that intergenerational wealth concentration has 
increased over the past two decades (Schulenberg et al. 2024): 
-  children from parents in the top 1% of the wealth distribution are on average 7 

percentiles higher in the wealth distribution in 2022 than in 2006.  

-  children from parents in the bottom 10% of the wealth distribution are on average 2 

percentiles lower in the wealth distribution in 2022 than in 2006. 

 
These empirical findings are pertinent, because the greatest wealth transfer in the 
history of the Netherlands will take place over the next 20 years, when the baby boom 
generation will bequeath their companies, homes, investments and savings to the next 
generation.  
 

Policy recommendations 

 
Given these facts about inequality in the Netherlands, policy interventions are 
necessary to enhance broad prosperity. In this position paper, I identify three low-
hanging fruits: 
 
Policy recommendation 1: Close loopholes in the Dutch tax system 
The tax system needs to be monitored and maintained permanently to ensure it 
achieves the aims and intentions of the policymakers and politicians who created it. A 
priority here should be the closing of loopholes. 
 
Various remarkable fiscal structures (‘opmerkelijke belastingconstructies’) have 
emerged over time. These are conscious attempts to structure and/or shift income, 
profits, transactions, and wealth to reduce one’s tax burden by exploiting differences in 
rates, exemptions, and tax base definitions (Reiding, Timmerman, Nissen 2023). Several 
of these fiscal structures have been reported on extensively by researchers and 
policymakers (IBO vermogensverdeling 2022, 79-87, appendix 10), such as improper 
use of the business succession scheme (‘bedrijfsopvolgingsregeling’), box hopping 
between box 2 and box 3, and putting companies in the name of infants (‘baby bv’).  
 
These fiscal structures can lead to tax revenue shortfalls and tax regressivity (i.e., 
imposing a smaller tax burden on those who are wealthier). It is important to note that 
even when only few people make use of a particular fiscal structure (such as the ‘baby 
bv’), its continued existence can undermine the perceived legitimacy of the tax system.  
 

background image

 

One structure that has not received much attention yet is giving gifts on paper 
(‘schenkingen op papier’) to next of kin and thereby reduce inheritance tax liability (see 
appendix 2 on how this works).   
  
Policy recommendation 2: Reform wealth income taxation 
Recent research from Zucman (2024) suggests that the overall tax burden is regressive 
for those in the top 10% of the income distribution in the Netherlands. Consider the 
following figure from Zucman’s report, which shows all taxes (including income, 
consumption, and corporate taxes) paid by different income groups at all levels of 
government in France, Italy, the Netherlands, and the United States:5  
     

 

 
One of the reasons why overall taxation is regressive in the Netherlands is that high net 
worth individuals use holding companies to avoid capital gains realization and 
dividend taxation. They can then borrow from these companies to fund consumption, 
buy real estate, and so on, without paying income tax. In the United States, two laws 
have been in place since the early twentieth century to prevent the use of holding 
companies for tax avoidance (Zucman 2024; see Saez & Zucman 2016 for details). In 
the Netherlands, the 2023 ‘excessive borrowing act’ (‘wet excessief lenen’) is a step in 
the right direction, restricting the amount that can be borrowed to € 500.000. 

 

5  These countries, taken together, “host about 35% of global billionaires and account for about 40% of 
global billionaire wealth” (Zucman 2024, 10). They are among the very few countries for which data on 
effective tax rates paid by different wealth deciles and billionaires is available.  

background image

 

Unfortunately, however, home acquisition loans are currently exempted (also when 
such loans are provided to children and grandchildren). Removing this exemption 
would help in addressing tax regressivity at the top of the income distribution. 
 
Moreover, the current tax on income from saving and investment (box 3) is based on 
hypothetical returns (1,44% return on savings and 6,04% return on other investments in 
2024). Because those with greater wealth have higher returns on their portfolio’s (Bach, 
Calvet, Sodini 2020), this system can amplify wealth inequality. A system that instead 
taxes actual returns would be preferable.  
 
Policy recommendation 3: Modernize and reform inheritance taxation 
Political philosophers ranging from libertarians (Nozick 1989) to (socialist) egalitarians 
(Robeyns forthcoming; White 2008) all advocate for inheritance taxation. Libertarians 
are worried about intergenerational wealth transfers undermining people’s freedom, 
whereas egalitarians are concerned that such transfers threaten substantive equality of 
opportunity. This convergence is noteworthy, especially because inheritance taxation is 
unpopular with the general population.  
 
In the Netherlands, the median inheritance was 39.300 euros, and the average 
inheritance 165.400 euros in 2022 (CBS 2025b). Taxing small inheritances is 
burdensome for the tax office and could undermine public support for inheritance 
taxation. One option would be to exempt all inheritances below 50.000 euros and then 
apply a more progressive rate on inheritances above the exemption, to compensate for 
the resulting revenue shortfalls. It is also advisable to revise current rate differentiation 
based on the recipient’s relationship with the deceased, which highly favours 
children—and, to a lesser extent, grandchildren (for the current rates, see appendix 3). 
This set-up incentivizes wealth concentration within families, which, as pointed out, is 
on the rise in the Netherlands.  
 
References 
Arts, Koos, & Noortje Pouwels-Urlings. 2020. “Pensioenvermogen en 

vermogensongelijkheid.” Centraal Bureau voor Statistiek. Retrieved on 7 May 
2025 from <https://www.cbs.nl/nl-nl/longread/statistische-
trends/2020/pensioenvermogen-en-vermogensongelijkheid?onepage=true>. 

Bach, Laurent, Laurent Calvert, Paolo Sodini. 2020. “Rich Pickings? Risk, Return, and 

Skill in Household Wealth.” American Economic Review 110(9): 2703-2747. 

CBS. 2021. “De verscheidenheid van Nederlandse huishoudens: update” Retrieved on 

29 April 2025 from <https://www.cpb.nl/sites/default/files/omnidownload/CPB-
Achtergronddocument-verscheidenheid-vermogens-Nederlandse-huishoudens-
update.pdf> 

CBS. 2022. “Bovenaan welvaartsladder bijna 25 jaar langer in goede gezondheid.” 

Retrieved on 28 April 2025 from <https://www.cbs.nl/nl-
nl/nieuws/2022/51/bovenaan-welvaartsladder-bijna-25-jaar-langer-in-goede-
gezondheid>. 

CBS. 2025a. “Bestaande koopwoningen; verkoopprijzen prijsindex 2015=100 1995-

2023.” Retrieved on 29 April 2025 from <https://www.cbs.nl/nl-
nl/cijfers/detail/83906NED> 

background image

 

CBS. 2025b. “Nalatenschappen; nagelaten vermogen, kenmerken.” Retrieved on 2 May 

2025 from <

 https://www.cbs.nl/nl-nl/cijfers/detail/84242NED>. 

Chetty, Raj, Michael Stepner, Sarah Abraham, Shelby Lin, Bejamin Scuderi, Nicholas 

Turner, Augstin Bergeron, David Cutler. 2016. “The Association Between 
Income and Life Expectancy in the United States, 2001-2014.” Journal of the 
American Medical Association 315
(16): 1750 – 1766. 

CPB. 2024. “Macro-Economische Verkenning 2025.” Verzamelde bijlagen met lange 

reeksen. Retrieved on 29 April 2025 from < https://www.cpb.nl/raming-
september-2024-mev-2025>. 

Hoff, Stella, and Bart van Hulst. 2019. “Armoede bij kinderen en volwassenen: Kans op 

armoede het grootst voor de jongsten én alleroudsten in de bevolking.” 
Retrieved on 29 April 2025 from < 
https://digitaal.scp.nl/armoedeinkaart2019/armoede-bij-kinderen-en-
volwassenen/>. 

IBO vermogensverdeling. 2022. “Licht uit, spot aan: de vermogensverdeling.” Retrieved 

on 29 April 2025 from <https://open.overheid.nl/documenten/ronl-
c2da23e05fef0df2b0cd79ff09c88c673d3b3e95/pdf>. 

Kadaster. 2025. “Woningmarkt 1e kwartaal 2025: starters kochten in steden, 

doorstromers daarbuiten.” Retrieved on 2 May 2025 from 
<https://www.kadaster.nl/-/woningmarkt-1e-kwartaal-2025-starters-kochten-in-
steden-doorstromers-daarbuiten>. 

Knoef, Marike, Jim Been, Koen Caminada, Kees Goudswaard, Jason Rhuggenaath. 

2017. “De toereikendheid van de pensioenopbouw na de crisis en 
pensioenhervormingen.” Netspar Industry Paper Series. Design paper 68. 
Retrieved on 7 May 2025 from <https://www.netspar.nl/wp-
content/uploads/Netspar-Design-Paper-68-WEB.pdf>. 

Muns, Sander, Marike Knoef, Arthur van Soest. 2018. “Verschil in levensverwachting 

tussen lage en hoge inkomens is verder gestegen.” Me Judice. Retrieved on 28 
April 2025, from < https://www.mejudice.nl/artikelen/detail/verschil-in-
levensverwachting-tussen-lage-en-hoge-inkomens-is-verder-gestegen>  

Nozick, Robert. The Examined Life: Philosophical Meditations. New York: Simon & 

Schuster. 

NVM. 2025. ”Marktinformatie koopwoningen.” Retrieved on 29 April 2025 from 

<https://www.nvm.nl/wonen/marktinformatie/> 

Piketty, Thomas. 2014. Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard 

University Press. 

Reiding, Arieke, Jolanda Timmerman, Rens Nissen. 2023. “Pak belastingconstructies 

aan via groot onderhoud van huidig belastingstelsel.” ESB. Retrieved on 2 May 
2025 from <https://esb.nu/pak-belastingconstructies-aan-via-groot-onderhoud-
van-huidig-belastingstelsel/>. 

Robeyns, Ingrid. forthcoming 2025. “Limiting Lifetime Inheritances and Gifts. Politics, 

Philosophy, and Economics.   

Saez, Emmanuel, and Gabriel Zucman. 2016. “Wealth Inequality in the United States 

since 1913: Evidence from Capitalized Income Tax Data.” Quarterly Journal of 
Economics 131
(2): 519-578. 

Schulenberg, René, Céline van Essen, Esther Hamelink, Arjan Lejour. 2024. “Een 

duwtje in de rug: vermogenmobiliteit van ouder op kind.” CPB. Retrieved on 29 

background image

 

April 2025 from < https://www.cpb.nl/sites/default/files/omnidownload/CPB-
publicatie-een-steuntje-in-de-rug-vermogensmobiliteit-van-ouders-op-kind.pdf>. 

SER. 2023. “Gezond opgroeien, wonen en werken: naar een structurele 

gezondheidsaanpak en bestrijding van sociaal-economische 
gezondheidsverschillen.” Advies 23/07. Retrieved on 29 April 2025 from 
<https://www.ser.nl/-/media/ser/downloads/adviezen/2023/gezond-opgroeien-
wonen-werken.pdf>.  

Toussaint, Simon J. 2024. Accounting for Wealth Concentration. PhD thesis. U.S.E. 

dissertation series 079.  

Toussaint, Simon J., Amaury de Vicq, Michail Moatsos, Tim van der Valk. 2024. 

“Wealth Inequality in a Small, Open Economy: The Netherlands, 1854-2019.” 
Unpublished manuscript. For an earlier version, see World Inequality Database, 
retrieved on 28 April 2025 from <https://wid.world/news-article/household-
wealth-and-its-distribution-in-the-netherlands-1854-2019/>. 

Waldenström, Daniel. 2024. Richer & More Equal: A New History of Wealth in the 

West. Cambridge: Polity Press. 

White, Stuart. 2008. “What (if Anything) is Wrong with Inheritance Taxation?” The 

Political Quarterly 79(2): 162-171. 

Zucman, Gabriel. 2024. “A Blueprint for a Coordinated Minimum Effective Taxation 

Standard for Ultra-High-Net-Worth Individuals.” Report prepared for G7 
presidency. Retrieved on 29 April 2025 from <https://gabriel-
zucman.eu/files/report-g20.pdf> 

 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 

background image

 

Appendix 1: Wealth and pension II capital by education level 
Taken from Arts & Pouwels-Urlings (2020, table 3.9) 
 

Age 

Education level 

Average wealth 
without pillar II 
capital 

Average pillar II 
pension capital 

Total (wealth + 
pillar II pension 
capital) 

Total 

Low 

 €           115.700    €             91.900    €             207.600  

Total 

Middle 

 €           160.000    €           135.900    €             295.900  

Total 

High 

 €           262.100    €           241.100    €             503.200  

younger than 35   Low 

 €             17.400    €             10.000    €               27.400  

younger than 35   Middle 

 €             25.800    €             16.600    €               42.400  

younger than 35   High 

 €             49.600    €             26.300    €               75.900  

35 till 55  

Low 

 €             73.500    €             66.200    €             139.700  

35 till 55  

Middle 

 €           132.700    €           108.900    €             241.600  

35 till 55  

High 

 €           230.500    €           181.700    €             412.200  

55 till 75  

Low 

 €           153.300    €           152.500    €             305.800  

55 till 75  

Middle 

 €           262.500    €           263.800    €             526.300  

55 till 75  

High 

 €           421.500    €           481.900    €             903.400  

older than 75 

Low 

 €           150.500    €             58.000    €             208.500  

older than 75 

Middle 

 €           253.900    €           106.800    €             360.700  

older than 75 

High 

 €           450.200    €           246.000    €             696.200  

 
 
 

 

background image

 

10 

Appendix 2: Calculation gifts on paper 
Thanks to dr. Nicole Gubbels (Tilburg University) for the calculation 
 
Gifts to children are exempted from gift taxation up to an amount of € 6.713 per year 
(2025 exemption, see appendix 3). A common way of avoiding inheritance taxation is 
to not actually transfer gifts to children, but give them ‘on paper’, and then pay children 
interest as compensation for not actually having transferred the gift. When the giver 
passes away, these gifts on paper are deducted from children’s inheritance. No 
inheritance tax has to be paid on the interest payments.  
 
Regular gifts 
Parent gives € 6.000 every year, during a period of 50 years, to their child  
Total 50 x € 6.000 = 

 

  

 

 

 

€ 300.000  

Reduction in inheritance taxation (20% x € 300.000) = 

€   60.000 

 
Gifts on paper 
Debt at moment of passing (50 x € 6.000) =  

 

 

€ 300.000 

Yearly interest payment (6%), in total ≈   

 

 

€   40.000 

Reduction in inheritance taxation (20% x € 340.000) = 

€   68.000 

 
 
 
 
Appendix 3: Gift and inheritance taxation rates 
 

Value gift or 
inheritance 

Partner, 
children 

Grandchildren and 
further descendants  

Other benificiaries 

up till € 154.197 

10% 

18% 

30% 

from € 154.197 

20% 

36% 

40% 

 
The following exemptions apply to the gift tax in 2025: 

•  Children, annually: € 6.713 

•  Children, one off: expensive education (€ 67.064) or any other aim (€ 32.195) 
•  Anyone else, annually: € 2.690 

 
The following exemptions apply to the inheritance tax in 2025: 

• 

Partners: € 804.698 

• 

Children and grandchildren: € 25.490 

• 

Great-grandchildren: € 2.690 

• 

Sick and disabled children: € 76.453 

• 

Parents: € 60.359 

• 

Other beneficiaries: € 2.690